• News
    • Latest news
    • News search
    • Health
    • Finance
    • Food
    • Career news
    • Content series
    • Try Devex Pro
  • Jobs
    • Job search
    • Post a job
    • Employer search
    • CV Writing
    • Upcoming career events
    • Try Career Account
  • Funding
    • Funding search
    • Funding news
  • Talent
    • Candidate search
    • Devex Talent Solutions
  • Events
    • Upcoming and past events
    • Partner on an event
  • Post a job
  • About
      • About us
      • Membership
      • Newsletters
      • Advertising partnerships
      • Devex Talent Solutions
      • Contact us
Join DevexSign in
Join DevexSign in

News

  • Latest news
  • News search
  • Health
  • Finance
  • Food
  • Career news
  • Content series
  • Try Devex Pro

Jobs

  • Job search
  • Post a job
  • Employer search
  • CV Writing
  • Upcoming career events
  • Try Career Account

Funding

  • Funding search
  • Funding news

Talent

  • Candidate search
  • Devex Talent Solutions

Events

  • Upcoming and past events
  • Partner on an event
Post a job

About

  • About us
  • Membership
  • Newsletters
  • Advertising partnerships
  • Devex Talent Solutions
  • Contact us
  • My Devex
  • Update my profile % complete
  • Account & privacy settings
  • My saved jobs
  • Manage newsletters
  • Support
  • Sign out
Latest newsNews searchHealthFinanceFoodCareer newsContent seriesTry Devex Pro
    Sponsored Content
    Center for Global Development
    • News
    • News
    • From our partner

    Cutting aid after a coup may be a bad response

    Should donors cut aid to a country after a political shock like a coup? Martin Ravallion, non-resident fellow at the Center for Global Development, analyzes why donors sometimes do not know best and why withdrawing assistance can make things worse.

    By Devex Editor // 02 July 2013
    Hundreds of protesters at the 2009 Malagasy rally to oust Marc Ravalomanana, then president of Madagascar. The heightened tension of the coup forced international aid donors and foreign investments to pull out of the country. Photo by: r1_lita / CC BY-NC-SA

    EDITOR’S NOTE: Should donors cut aid to a country after a political shock like a coup? Martin Ravallion, non-resident fellow at the Center for Global Development, analyzes why sometimes donors do not know best and why withdrawing assistance can make things worse.

    Cutting development assistance to a country after some negative political shock is undoubtedly a well-intentioned effort by donors to incentivize better political institutions. Aid donors do not want to be seen to support coups, which would come with reputational and political risks at home. Instead, the argument is made that donors should offer a carrot and a stick to developing countries to encourage better institutions.

    There are some concerns with this argument. Do the donors know best? Are rich country political institutions ideal for poor countries? How much of the incentive is felt by coup leaders, or are the costs borne largely by innocent citizens, including the poor?

    Here I would like to focus on another issue. This is prompted by thinking about the economics of institutional development. This suggests that there is a real, but little recognized, risk that this type of response by aid donors will only make things worse, with a potentially large and lasting cost to institutional development.

    What we may well have here is a plausible situation of multiple equilibria in the development of political institutions. Let me try to explain. I take it as a given that external assistance (both technical and financial) can help develop political, legal and administrative institutions that are good for longer-term development including eliminating poverty. Some aid skeptics out there may disagree, but I think it plausible that external assistance can help promote well-defined property rights, a higher quality of fiscal management, more efficient revenue mobilization, greater transparency and accountability in the public sector and a better quality of public administration generally; in short, more capable states. These are the aspects of institutions that are emphasized by the World Bank’s Country Policy and Institutional Assessments. Naturally these things take time, and patience is needed.

    I also take it as plausible that little or no external or domestic effort will be forthcoming if the country’s institutions are just too dysfunctional to start off with. There is some minimum threshold that must be reached to have any hope of helping to develop better institutions. (Think of this as a very low score in the World Bank’s CPIA, which would essentially kill aid from the bank, and most donors.) And I take it as likely that both external assistance and domestic efforts will start to stabilize and even decline when institutions are sufficiently well developed. 

    Putting these elements together (and with some more technical economic assumptions that need not bother us here) we have the makings of a classic story of multiple equilibria, known to economists as a “poverty trap,” although here I will call it a “poor institutions trap” — a PIT. The following picture helps explain how a developing country can get into a PIT, despite otherwise good initial conditions, favorable to development.

    On the vertical axis we have “future institutional quality” while on the horizontal axis we have “today’s institutional quality.” We see the threshold labeled Imin. Once that is reached, external assistance combines with complementary efforts by citizens and governments to generate better institutions. After some time, when institutional quality is reasonably high, the effort moves to other places and tasks where it is needed more.

    We can identify three “steady-state equilibria” — essentially meaning points at which institutions have stabilized for a given country. Point A is the PIT — the worst case in which persistently bad institutions prevail. Point C is where the country needs to be. Between these two equilibria, we have point B. This is clearly better than A, but alas it is dynamically unstable.

    To better understand the implications of this instability, imagine a small positive shock to institutions in a country at its point B. This will put the country on a virtuous cycle, progressing toward point C. But a negative shock will create a vicious cycle — a downward spiral all the way into the PIT, at point A. And getting out of the PIT will not be possible with a small positive incentive for reform; then the country will just bounce back into the PIT in due course. Getting out of the PIT will require a more substantial gain in institutional quality (to get past point B) than simply reversing the (possibly small) shock that landed the country in a PIT.

    I suggest that some poor countries today are at their middle point B, while others are at A. For example, I am willing to conjecture that Madagascar was at its own “point B” prior to the coup in 2009. In the wake of the coup, development assistance contracted markedly (by about half), tourism slumped (apparently it is even hard to get travel insurance to Madagascar) and an already poor country got poorer. Unlike much of the developing world, Madagascar has made no progress against absolute poverty for many years, and by some measures things have got worse. The political crisis continues.

    The international community’s decision to pull out in response to the coup in Madagascar was no doubt seen as providing an incentive for a rapid rebound to democracy, and a favorable continuing trajectory of development. But when viewed in terms of my model, the impact may well have been much larger than expected, by helping to put the country in a PIT. I don’t know for sure if that is the case, but nor do the donors. And there are big risks to poor people in decisions made in ignorance. At a minimum, we should try to better understand the dynamics of institutional development — to see whether the PIT model I have sketched above is realistic, and what implications this holds for development assistance. That is not an easy research question, but it surely reflects an important knowledge gap in our understanding of development.

    If my characterization is roughly right then the lesson for aid donors is clear: By all means be willing to reward positive political shocks, but be careful about punishing negative ones. Given the instability, this response may well help put longer term institutional development in the country back even further. A more prudent approach may well be to maintain the baseline of assistance, stay engaged on the planned development path and remind all of the benefits of doing so. This path should include support for better political institutions. But be wary of cutting aid in poor and fragile economies when there is a negative political shock. That stick you are wielding may hurt far more than you think!

    Edited for style and republished with permission from the Center for Global Development. Read the original article.

      Printing articles to share with others is a breach of our terms and conditions and copyright policy. Please use the sharing options on the left side of the article. Devex Pro members may share up to 10 articles per month using the Pro share tool ( ).

      About the author

      • Devex Editor

        Devex Editor

        Thanks a lot for your interest in Devex News. To share news and views, story ideas and press releases, please email editor@devex.com. We look forward to hearing from you.

      Search for articles

      Related Stories

      Economic developmentFrom 'aid trap' to 'brutal' cuts: African leaders confront a new reality

      From 'aid trap' to 'brutal' cuts: African leaders confront a new reality

      Devex Pro LiveUK aid cuts: 6 things left to fight for

      UK aid cuts: 6 things left to fight for

      PhilanthropyAmid aid cuts, the future of cash programming hangs in the balance

      Amid aid cuts, the future of cash programming hangs in the balance

      Devex Money MattersMoney Matters: Even before Trump, aid dollars were falling

      Money Matters: Even before Trump, aid dollars were falling

      Most Read

      • 1
        Opinion: How climate philanthropy can solve its innovation challenge
      • 2
        The legal case threatening to upend philanthropy's DEI efforts
      • 3
        Why supporting small, rural businesses is key to local economic growth
      • 4
        Why most of the UK's aid budget rise cannot be spent on frontline aid
      • 5
        Exclusive: A first look at the Trump administration's UNGA priorities
      • News
      • Jobs
      • Funding
      • Talent
      • Events

      Devex is the media platform for the global development community.

      A social enterprise, we connect and inform over 1.3 million development, health, humanitarian, and sustainability professionals through news, business intelligence, and funding & career opportunities so you can do more good for more people. We invite you to join us.

      • About us
      • Membership
      • Newsletters
      • Advertising partnerships
      • Devex Talent Solutions
      • Post a job
      • Careers at Devex
      • Contact us
      © Copyright 2000 - 2025 Devex|User Agreement|Privacy Statement